Modelling International Groups: The Relation Between Goals, Power, and Effectiveness

 

Le Palais des Nations, in Geneva (AWM)

I first developed this model in late 2008, refining it in 2010 and 2012. I heavily revised it in 2018, the year that Canada hosted the G7 Summit (I thank Jim Haley for his helpful comments). The views expressed here are entirely my own. . A PDF version is available here

 

Abstract

The effectiveness of an international group depends on the relationship between the member countries’ shared goals and their overall power. A group can only be effective if these two factors are aligned: goals that do not correspond to power are merely aspirational and powers unlinked to goals are useless.

A group should only expand its membership if two conditions are met: first, the new country must generally accept the group’s existing goals. Second, the new country’s powers should help to achieve the group’s existing shared goals. This framework helps to explain certain phenomena, such as why superpowers are reluctant to join groups, how changes in one country’s policies can affect an entire group’s effectiveness, and why adding powerful new members can make a group less effective overall.

There are four major implications for the current state of global governance. First, the G20 is likely to remain ineffective, as it operates based on consensus. The G20 should be refocused as a discussion forum, a task to which it is ideally suited. Second, although the current US administration opposes many traditional G20 policies, the US remains an essential G20 participant. Third, the G7 should focus on issues where its members have the power to bring about change themselves and abandon more ambitious goals. Finally, if the G20 were reformed so that it no longer operated on consensus (for example, by restricting veto power), it could be much more effective—assuming its members accepted such a change

 

Introduction


Suit the word to the action, the action to the word. 
Hamlet, III.ii

 
The Trump administration’s “America First” policy has led to new tensions in international governance, evident at major international meetings since early 2017. From disputes over climate change at the G20 Summit in Hamburg (July 2017), to arguments over trade protectionism in the lead up to the G7 Summit in Charlevoix (June 2018), the United States has expressed fundamental disagreements with policies long-endorsed by these forums.[1]

In one sense, this is deeply strange: over 2016-18, the membership of neither the G7 nor the G20 changed. There was been no major new international economic or security crisis. Several countries saw changes in leadership (such as Italy and France), but this is a normal part of the international meetings cycle. Instead, a change in US political leadership (and without corresponding change in underlying US economic or military power) was sufficient to prevent consensus.

The effect of this ideological shift reveals an important aspect of the structure of international groups: when decisions require unanimous consent, a loss in like-mindedness can hobble a group’s effectiveness—even when overall power of the various members remains unchanged. By examining how goals, powers, and effectiveness are interrelated, we can draw broader conclusions about the strengths and weaknesses of not just the G7 and the G20, but any international group. This in turn provides insight into possible ways to strengthen international groups.

 

Defining Goals, Power, and Effectiveness

In brief, individual countries have various policy goals and various powers; successful statecraft requires aligning the two. For example, Athens may wish to conquer new territory. If it possesses a well-trained military, it can use this aspect of its power to bring about this goal, thereby effectively implementing policy. In contrast, Melos—the object of Athens’ ambitions—may wish to avoid invasion. However, if Melos lacks a powerful military, it will lack the power to bring about this goal and be ineffective.

Countries are effective only when goals and powers match: goals that cannot be achieved are merely aspirational and powers unlinked to goals are useless. (Athens could also use its military to attack the much-larger Persian Empire; though this is within Athenian power, it is opposed to Athens’ goal of self-preservation.) Some countries will be more effective than others, either due to having broader powers or narrower goals. For example, in this sense, between 1920 and 1939, the USSR became more effective both by strengthening its industrial base (allowing for greater military mechanization) and by adopting the doctrine of “Socialism in One Country” and rejecting worldwide revolution (this being a difficult goal.)

Goals, power, and effectiveness can be defined as follows:

  • Each country has individual goals, gi. These are both active (policies it wants to pursue) and passive (policies it can accept, if others implement them.) Goals can be changed in the short term and at relatively little cost.
  • Each country also has individual powers, pi. These encompass the ability to act in any way, for positive or negative effect. Powers are relatively static and change only in the long term.
  • Whenever goals and powers overlap, the country is capable of an effective action, ei. Goals that do not align with powers and powers that do not align with goals are irrelevant.
  • Effective actions are associated with some positive utility, u(ei).
These three definitions can be modelled using Venn diagrams by presenting effectiveness as the intersection between goals and power.

Figure 1: Goals, Power, and Effectiveness


 

Group Effectiveness

By forming groups, countries can pool their individual powers to achieve shared goals. For example, the resources of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) include Saudi Arabia’s oil and Bahrain’s natural gas, giving the GCC significant influence on international energy issues.

When countries join a group, the effect on goals is more complex. Most major international groups are characterized by three features: they are veto-based (operating by consensus), senatorial (each member has one representative or vote, regardless of its size), and utility maximizing (countries join groups because they hope to become more effective.) These features hold at the UN Security Council, the G20, the G7, the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation forum (APEC), most free trade agreements, and a host of other military alliances, treaties, and informal groupings. The three rules reflect a balance between powerful countries’ unwillingness to surrender veto power and smaller countries’ desire for equal representation.

Of note, certain international groups violate the first two rules,[2] such as the UN General Assembly (which is not veto-based), the European Central Bank (which is not senatorial, as only a subset of members participate in board decisions), and the International Monetary Fund (which is not senatorial, awarding votes based on economic weight, nor veto-based.) Despite this, it is telling that the most powerful international groups, as well as most groups that meet at the level of leaders, are veto-based and senatorial.

Returning to Venn diagrams, given the additive nature of power, a group’s overall power is the union of the individual powers of the member countries. In contrast, when veto power exists, common goals are the intersection of the individual goals of the member countries.

Figure 2: Overall Power and Common Goals (Three Countries)


These relationships allow us to model the effectiveness of an international group. Crucially, the effectiveness of a group is not the same as the combined effectiveness of the individual members. Instead, groups entail combinations of goals and powers that allow countries to achieve actions that are not possible for any of them unilaterally.

The Lend-Lease agreement in the Second World War provides an example: over 1942-45, the UK had airfields within range of Germany, while the US had the capacity to build numerous aircraft. Through Lend-Lease, the two countries achieved their common goal (attacking Germany) by combining their powers (using US-made planes using UK airbases.) This would have been impossible for either country to achieve unilaterally (i.e., their individual goals and powers did not align in these respects.)

A group’s effectiveness is thus the intersection of its common goals and its overall power. This is distinct from the union or intersection of the effectiveness of the individual members. (For a proof of this, please see Annex 1.) 

Figure 3: Group Effectiveness (Two Countries) 


There is a further and more cynical implication of this relationship: disputes over aspirational goals do not undermine effectiveness. Even if countries dispute goals that are beyond their power, this in no way affects their ability to enact other goals that are common and within their power. In this light, the alleged disagreement between Roosevelt and Churchill at Yalta over Stalin’s intentions in Eastern Europe was irrelevant, as neither the US nor the UK had forces stationed there that could have countered Soviet domination. Despite this disagreement, the rationale for Lend-Lease remained.

 

Membership Dynamics

Joining a group involves tradeoffs: due to the exercise of veto power, members must forbear from carrying out certain effective actions they could otherwise achieve unilaterally. To return to the Lend-Lease analogy, the terms of the agreement made it impossible for either the UK or the US to seek a separate peace with Germany. 

Joining a group is only desirable when the utility of the group’s effective actions exceeds the utility of unilateral actions. (As a corollary to this, superpowers have little incentive to join groups, as they are highly effective on their own.) The tradeoffs can be illustrated as follows. (Again, please see Annex 1 for a fully annotated version of this diagram.)

Figure 4: Tradeoffs in Effectiveness 



Applying the Lend-Lease example to Figure 4, with Country 1 as the US and Country 2 as the UK, “C” represents “build numerous warplanes” and “E” represents “use airbases within range of Germany.” “A” and “F” represent “sign a separate treaty with Germany,” while “D” could represent “engage in naval warfare against Germany” (advantageous to both countries, whether done jointly or unilaterally.)

Over time, groups are also affected by changes in their member countries. When a country adopts the group’s goals (a form of international “socialization”) the group’s effectiveness increases. The reverse case, as illustrated by the Trump administration actions in the G7 and G20, reduces effectiveness.

Though changes in individual power occur more slowly, they too alter group effectiveness. For example, advances in US intelligence gathering capabilities have benefitted its “Five Eyes” allies. Conversely, Indonesia’s gradual decline as an oil exporter has reduced OPEC’s global market share. 

Figure 5: Socialization and the Balance of Power  



 

Expansion and Expulsion

A critical question for any group is whether to alter its membership, either by welcoming new members or expelling existing ones. Focusing on the alignment between goals and power is essential to understand the subtle effects of changes in membership. While power is always additive (adding a country can never reduce overall power) and common goals are never additive (adding a country can never broaden the scope of common goals), group effectiveness can either increase or decrease.

Merely seeking to balance like-mindedness and power is imprecise: what is required instead is strategic consideration of how the country’s specific goals and powers will influence future group effectiveness. Though Country A disagrees with the rest of the group on several issues, could it help to achieve a crucial shared goal? (During the Confederation of Canada, Prince Edward Island partly resisted union, but eventually was won over.) Though Country B supports all the group’s initiatives, is it merely free-riding, offering little new power? (Japan’s joining the alliance against Germany during the First World War allowed it to seize German colonies in the Pacific, with limited effects on the European theater.)

The formation of the United States presents an immensely successful example of sovereign governments forming together with the explicit goal of pursuing common goals. Capital-rich northern states joined agriculture-rich southern states, allowing greater economic growth than either could achieve alone, as well as facilitating mutual defense.

In contrast, Russia’s participation in the G7/G8 was a failure. Russia was invited into the G7/G8 at the 1997 Denver Summit, despite did not sharing many of the old G7’s existing goals or priorities.  Even so, it was hoped that participation in the group would socialize Russia, encouraging it to embrace G7 views. When Russia invaded Crimea in 2014, the original G7 members recognized that there was an irreconcilable ideological gulf, and Russia was expelled. Although Russia wielded significant power over core G8 issues (such as nuclear disarmament and counterterrorism), because it did not share the old G7’s goals, the G8 was ineffective overall.

As a final consideration, countries may join multiple groups to achieve discrete goals, even when the larger groups oppose each other. For example, in return for sharing intelligence with both countries, Pakistan receives support from China and the US. Groups may understandably wish to discourage this type of behavior: indeed, most Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) contain provisions against “transshipment.” For example, while Canada has agreements with the United States (NAFTA) and the EU (CETA), there is (as yet) no US-EU FTA.[3] Hence, it is forbidden to tranship goods tariff-free from the US to the EU via Canada

Figure 6: Multiple Groups

 

Conclusion & Implications

This analysis provides a new way to think about the relations between goals, power, and effectiveness. It is not enough simply to gather powerful countries together, nor to seek ideological uniformity before all else; such groups are either powerful but indecisive, or unified but powerless. Instead, a group’s effectiveness is determined by its power to implement its shared goals. Aspirational goals and useless powers are both irrelevant.

When expanding a group, the essential factors are whether the prospective new member’s individual powers will help to achieve the group’s existing shared goals, and the degree to which the new member accepts those goals.

Framing the problem in this way can provide clarity on certain phenomena, such as why superpowers are reluctant to join groups (they have a high degree of unilateral effectiveness), how changes in one country’s policies can affect an entire group’s effectiveness (by the scope of common goals), or why adding powerful new members can make a group less effective overall (through veto power.)

Admittedly, the model has limitations, notably the assumptions that all members wield veto power and that representation is senatorial (one country, one vote.) Furthermore, the assumption of utility maximization is limiting, as it discounts the possibility that countries may join groups for other reasons (such as a way to maintain dialogue.)

These principles have several implications for the current state of global governance:
1. Absent an immediate international crisis, the G20 is likely to be ineffective in terms of enacting shared policies. Despite this, the G20 can serve a useful purpose as a discussion forum. The G20 acted boldly and decisively during the Global Financial Crisis, launching $1 trillion in coordinated stimulus in 2009. At that time, all members shared the goal of avoiding a global financial collapse and they jointly employed their collective power. Since then, the G20 has struggled to achieve universal agreement on major issues, limiting the group’s effectiveness. Given that the G20 operates on a consensus basis, it is not realistic to expect major new “deliverables.” Instead, the G20 should be reimagined as a forum for discussion and the sharing of views, a task to which it is ideally suited.
 
2. Despite current squabbling with the United States, it is extremely unlikely that the G20 will expel or disengage with the US. American participation still is a net positive for G20 effectiveness. As did the G7 expelled Russia, so to could the G20 theoretically expel the US. Yet despite the current US administration’s opposition to the G20 consensus on climate change and trade, US participation raises the G20’s effectiveness in many other areas, such as countering terrorist financing and money laundering. Only if US power ceased to be relevant to the G20’s priorities would there be serious talk of suspension or expulsion.
 
3. The G7 should restrict its activities to areas where its members can bring about major change on their own. It should cease to present itself as a global steering group. The G7 should focus on those areas where its seven members have the power to bring about change, such as in the realm of development assistance. Though its seven members may be like-minded on many issues, G7 lacks the power to address issues like exchange rate policy. (Of note, G7 disagreements on global issues are not problematic, because the seven members lack the power to address such issues in any event. From a strategic perspective, the US veto on supporting climate change will have no impact on the G7’s overall effectiveness in other areas.)

A final and farther-reaching implication arises from this model. As changes in power take time, expanding the set of common goals is the quickest and simplest way to increase a group’s effectiveness. Aside from persuasion, this can also be brought about by changing the rules governing the group:

4. Relaxing constraints on veto power and representation can make a group more effective, by increasing the scope of common goals. There are numerous ways to achieve this, such as:
  • Restricting veto power to certain members (UN Security Council)
  • Restricting representation to certain members (European Central Bank)
  • Making decisions by votes, either with weighted votes (International Monetary Fund) or one country, one vote (UN General Assembly)
  • Requiring members to accept certain goals as a condition of membership in the group (the European Union)
  • Regular review of membership (UN Security Council, in part), with the aim of admitting countries that will increase effectiveness and expelling current members that reduce it
If the G20 were to embrace any of these rules, its effectiveness could increase significantly. At the same time, it is unclear whether countries would be willing to join such a group: veto power and senatorial representation are widely adopted because they are attractive to leaders.

The UN Security Council provides the most promising template for G20 reform on these lines: it is a widely-respected international group that operates with a limited veto and majority voting (based on one country, one vote), and it conducts regular reviews of its membership. With prospects of major Security Council reform dim, a transformed G20—repurposed as a “Global Economic Council”—could take up stewardship of the global economy, as the G20 so ably did in 2008-09, before it lost its way.

 

Annex 1: Detailed Analysis of Tradeoffs in a Group

This diagram illustrates the full set of possibilities when two countries form a group. Goals and powers can be divided into sixteen areas, one of which is empty (null.) Each area can be explained individually.

Note that in previous diagrams, for the sake of simplicity and clarity, areas 4 and 14, and extensions to areas 5 and 7 were not shown. But to show the full range of possibilities, the Venn diagram requires these regions (i.e., a country’s powers should have a “panhandle”, instead of being rectangular.)

 
 




Country A (red)
Country B (blue)
Group
Goals (circles)
(1, 2, 4, 5, 6, 7, 8, 12)
(6, 7, 8, 11, 12, 13, 14, 15)
(6, 7, 8, 12)
Powers (polygons)
(2, 3, 5, 7, 8, 9, 11, 14)
(4, 5, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 15)
(2, 3, 4, 5, 7, 8, 9, 10, 11, 12, 14, 15)
Effectiveness
(2, 5, 7, 8)
(8, 11, 12, 15)
(7, 8, 12)

Underlined: part of effectiveness

Italicized: shared with the group

Area
Explanation

Area
Explanation
1
Goals of A that it can never achieve (not alone and not in the group, as B would veto them)

9
Irrelevant: Useless powers shared by A and B (they do not correspond to A or B’s goals)
2
Effectiveness of A that it must surrender (it can achieve this alone, but it is vetoed in the group)

10
Irrelevant: Useless powers of B (they do not correspond to A or B’s goals)
3
Irrelevant: Useless powers of A (they do not correspond to A or B’s goals)

11
Effectiveness of B that it must surrender (it can achieve this alone, but it is vetoed in the group)
4
Irrelevant: powers of B that correspond to A’s goals, but not B’s goals

12
Effectiveness that B can achieve alone, and which A has as a goal. (A can only achieve this by joining the group.)
5
Effectiveness of A that it must surrender (it can achieve this alone, but it is vetoed in the group)

13
Goals of B that it can never achieve (not alone and not in the group, as A would veto them)
6
Shared goals of A and B that they can never achieve (not alone and not in the group.) The group should expand its powers into this area.

14
Irrelevant: powers of A that correspond to B’s goals, but not A’s goals
7
Effectiveness that A can achieve alone, and which B has as a goal. (B can only achieve this by joining the group.)

15
Effectiveness of B that it must surrender (it can achieve this alone, but it is vetoed in the group)
8
Effectiveness of A and B that is possible both alone and in the group

16
Null (empty)


Thus, Country A gives up its effectiveness in areas 2 and 5, but it gains effectiveness in area 12. Similarly, Country B gives up its effectiveness in areas 11 and 15, but it gains effectiveness in area 7. For the group to be effective, both the following must be true:

UA(12) > UA(2,5)

UA(7) > UA(11,15)

Further implications are that Country A has an incentive to minimize areas 2 and 5, which it can achieve by persuading Country B to share these goals. Country B has a similar incentive with regard to areas 11 and 15. Moreover, the group should also aim to expand its powers into area 6, as these are goals that both countries share, but which neither has the power to achieve unilaterally or in the group.

Finally, note that utility may not be evenly distributed across all areas.[4] For example, although area 12 may appear small in the above diagram, it could have an extremely high utility for Country A.

 

Annex 2: Mathematical Appendix

(Note: Due to time pressures, the mathematical expressions below are presented as JPEGs. They are included in line in the text in the PDF version.)
 
Below is a more formal treatment of the model, as well as an alternative definition of effectiveness (2j).


For (2j), see [5]

 For (3d), see [6]


 For (4e), see [7]





[1] The first-ever G20 Leaders Summit was convened by George W. Bush, in Washington in November 2008. In the coming months, member countries would take a strong stance against protectionism.
[2] Finding groups that do not exist for utilitarian reasons is more difficult. The Anglo-Portuguese Alliance, in effect since 1733, is an imperfect example: this agreement has greater symbolic than practical significance.
[3] Such as the long-mooted TTIP
[4] Consider a third dimension, with utility extending perpendicularly from the plane in a non-uniform way. This is analogous to surface integration.
[5] In words, the effectiveness of the group is the union of the effectiveness of the individual member countries contingent on the common goals of all other member countries. Taking a two-country example,
By distribution,

By 2h, when there are two countries, k1 = g2 and  k2 = g1, thus
This is seen in Figure 3 and also in Annex 1.
[6] In effect, the decrease in unilateral effectiveness due to the requirement to abide by the goals the group  must be offset by the gain in utility from acting jointly with other countries etc.
[7] Because ki, the set of common goals excluding country i, cannot include any goals that are specific to country i, i.e., any of the elements of gui.